
Written by Jeremy Lind, Doris Okenwa and Ian Scoones
In recent years, the gaze of global investment has been directed to Africa’s land and resources. Over the past decade, global capital from Europe, the Near East, China and elsewhere poured into land-based investments in industrialised agriculture in sub-Saharan Africa alongside green energy projects, oil exploration and other largescale infrastructural developments.
While many critique widespread ‘land grabbing’, it is often overlooked that many investment projects are in the drylands. These are home to a patchwork of pastoral and agro-pastoral societies, many that were marginalised by centralised state power and maligned as backwards by earlier ‘modernisation’ efforts to create sedentarised (and compliant) governable subjects. Violence and the destruction of livelihoods was the experience for many.
Set against such legacies of contestation and underdevelopment, global investors, project developers and national governments herald new largescale investment as transformational, ushering in new-found prosperity and secure livelihoods.
Now, more than a decade since the investment spike began in the pastoral drylands of Eastern Africa, it is possible to see how a new generation of projects are reconfiguring power, livelihoods and conflict. What do investments look like in Eastern Africa’s drylands? Do the diverse inhabitants of these lands benefit, or is this a new type of territorialisation? And what types of resistance, mobilization and activism are evident?
These questions are explored across thirteen different contexts of largescale investment in our new book, Land, Investment and Politics: Reconfiguring Eastern Africa’s Pastoral Drylands. Focussing on local cases, stretching from the Gulf of Aden ports on Somaliland’s coast in the north to the Kilombero rice developments in southern Tanzania, the book highlights diverse experiences and perspectives of investment from the bottom-up.
When largescale investments encounter local economies, the social and spatial outcomes do not reflect merely the state’s aspirations of ‘development’ or the interests of large global capital. The outcomes also intersect with local realities and aspirations. Seen from the dryland margins, struggles around the framing and meanings given to investments in oil, wind, livestock, land and water are the crux of many tensions.
Even the most elaborate plans of financiers, contractors and national governments come unstuck and are re-made in the likeness of not only states’ visions of modernity and ‘progress’, but also those of herders and small-town entrepreneurs in the pastoral drylands.
‘Seeing’ and responding to investments
Ports, pipelines, roads, wind farms and plantations are part of ‘high modernist’ visions of state actors at the centre as well as private capital across Eastern Africa. A type of ‘growth talk’ emphasises the presumed benefits of large outside investment for expanding markets and economic activities in marginal rural areas. Actors in national governments become gatekeepers to foreign investment and are well-positioned to benefit personally from deals.
Investors promote the benefits of project activity to residents of nearby communities, through the construction of new infrastructure, easing transport difficulties and promoting marketing activity, providing opportunities for work, and creating corporate social investments in bursaries, classrooms and the provision of water, for example. Yet, these efforts at corporate social responsibility have ignited debates around belonging, entitlements and inclusion. In Turkana in northern Kenya, tensions cropped up around the efforts of oil investors to curry favour with communities and stem any potential resistance through ‘participatory’ and ‘consultative’ processes, inadvertently creating asymmetric power relations.
State actors at the sub-national level may not see investments in the same way, however. The position of sub-national political administrations can waiver between embrace and hostility. Mixed views of large-scale investments often hold among local business elites, as well. Ultimately, investment is something to be welcomed, but the terms of inclusion in land deals, compensation, and contract and tendering opportunities dictate the nature of politics. For example, around new geothermal developments in Baringo in Kenya’s northern Rift Valley, Pokot elites are at the forefront of land privatisation, fencing the most valuable plots along new roads that connect geothermal sites with national infrastructure.
The views of other dryland residents – small-scale pastoralists and dryland farmers – cover a spectrum, from opposition and resistance to the perceived loss of key grazing resources and farmland, to accommodation in anticipation of deriving personal benefit, to simple antipathy. For example, residents of small settlements near the Lake Turkana Wind Power site, also in northern Kenya, blockaded roads to protest their alleged exclusion from investment benefits – including compensation for the extraction of sand and the felling of trees, as well as access to jobs. Even so, at the local level, there is no uniform opinion or interest: while young people seek an economic foothold, elders agitate to uphold precedence for grazing rights while women seek to safeguard cultural rights as well as work opportunities as cleaners and cooks for contractors.
Ambiguous outcomes, unclear ‘winners’
Exploring ways that largescale investments are ‘seen’ by stakeholders at various levels of project design, finance, and implementation brings into the frame the questions: investments for whom? In whose interests? And with what consequences?
The reconfiguration of land ownership and use, while perhaps not as dramatic as earlier ‘land grabbing’ debates feared, has been profound, creating a new politics of land and investment in the pastoral regions. Simple narratives of the ‘state’ and/or ‘investor’ versus ‘local people’ do not relay the more complex dynamics and assemblages of interests that mobilise behind, anticipate and pursue large-scale investments. In Ethiopia’s Awash Valley, local Afar elites have become complicit in seeking personal advantage from the state’s investments in sugar estates, which have dispossessed livestock-keepers from prime grazing areas.
Infrastructure and investments have ignited intense competition for and revaluation of land, as local elites, and other domestic and foreign investors, jostle to claim tracts of land. Far from resisting and obstructing investment, many have sought to position themselves to benefit from land and resource investments. In Somaliland, intense competition to command a favourable position in wider trade networks are evident in struggles to capture the expected windfall of the Berbera corridor development. A common saying in Somaliland – He who sits close to the cooking pot gets a good bone – is invoked by some far from infrastructure who worry they will miss out the benefits.
A major result is the heightened tensions across groups, between emergent local capitalists and those whose access to land is curtailed. Poorer pastoralists may gain employment to complement or replace their livestock-based livelihoods, while those with small-town businesses may profit from a boom in the economy, especially during establishment and construction phases.
Inequality and mobilisation from below
So, how do communities around the edges of big projects gain more than arbitrary compensation? Local governments and leadership need to be more creative in negotiating investments beyond the national government agreements with developers. It is crucial to demand clear terms of engagement and more long-term benefits for differentiated local stakeholders – not just one-off disbursements or short-term work.
While national governments often side with investment, citizens and civil society alike can press for accountability – through statutory human rights instruments, the implementation of land reforms to guard against grabbing, the enforcement of environmental regulations, and scrutiny of contracts by anti-corruption agencies, to name a few.
Meanwhile, as the book argues, the more imperceptible influences of investments on territory, as well as economy, politics, and citizenship, will accentuate inequalities and social difference that increasingly characterise dryland margins. While there is no simple view ‘from below’, resistance, mobilisation and subversion are something to anticipate as part of the ongoing development of infrastructure, land and resources across Africa’s drylands.
Publication information:
Lind, Jeremy, Okenwa, Doris, and Scoones, Ian. 2020. Land, Investment and Politics: Reconfiguring Eastern Africa’s Pastoral Drylands. Woodbridge: James Currey.
Link to open access introductory chapter:
https://opendocs.ids.ac.uk/opendocs/handle/20.500.12413/15458
Purchase information:
https://boydellandbrewer.com/land-investment-politics.html (discount code – BB135)
You can see more and follow the PASTRES project on Twitter and Instagram
Thanks go to you, your co-editors and, of course, the chapter authors for what appears to be a nuanced and much-needed view of complexities of pastoralist development in parts of East Africa. I look forward to reading the book and, more, nothing in what follows is meant to detract from its contribution.
I also appreciate that my two questions to you may sound like questions about a book I wished had been written rather than the one actually written. So my apologies upfront for not reading the book first before asking two questions prompted by your necessarily brief PASTRES contribution:
Question #1. I confess your reference to “Pokot elites” and Turkana “elders” made me smile, because when I was there in the early 1980s, they were neither elderly nor elites all. I’m also pretty sure had I interviewed some of them at that time I’d have considered them as “poor pastoralists.” This is important because an over-arching development aim of the first-generation ASAL programs in these and adjacent districts was to help then-poor pastoralists to become better off.
So my question: What happens when poor pastoralists do become better off? Is there a point at which better-off pastoralists are not poor enough to merit further positive attention? Or to rephrase the question from the opposite direction: “Under what conditions do pastoralists, initially poor but now better off, become negative elites?”
Question #2. One obvious response to the prior questions is to point out that poor pastoralists becoming wealthier can and has increased inequalities. I certainly do not disagree with this repeated finding.
But my preceding questions still stand. For, as I remember it, the early 1980s development narratives in Kenya’s ASALs were never that “everyone must be lifted out of poverty at the same time.” If anything, those of us who had oversight of Kenya’ ASAL programs were—rightfully then as now—criticized for implementing, say, new water projects that fell far short of meeting even the growth rate of the population in the ASALs, let alone the water needs of everyone else there.
Which leads to my last question: When did the development narrative become “all poor pastoralists must develop at the same rate and at a faster rate than rich pastoralists?” Might it be possible that such a development aim is even more difficult to implement than, say, new water projects there in the 1980s?
To be clear, I ask these question out of honest curiosity and in no way to suggest the plights you and your colleagues identify are not the plights that deserve much more attention.
LikeLike